麻豆社madou

Media contact

Ben Knight
麻豆社madou Media & Content
(02) 9065 4915
b.knight@unsw.edu.au

Social housing in Australia has been in neglect for more than two decades. With聽, ballooning waitlists and exploding queueing times across the country from minimal investment, the sector desperately needs a way to fund the construction of new below-market rent dwellings 鈥 and quickly.

With the support of the Greens, Labor鈥檚 $10 billion聽Housing Australia Future Fund (HAFF) has finally passed the Senate. This will usher in a new funding mechanism enabling publicly subsidised, privately financed, social and affordable housing development.

鈥淪uperfunds and other institutional players are looking for new investment opportunities, and governments are looking to boost social housing construction while minimising new debt on the public balance sheet,鈥 says Professor Hal Pawson, Associate Director at . 鈥淲ith the HAFF framework, Australia has a new national match-funding mechanism to enable institutional investment, which will help expand much-needed social housing production.鈥

How will聽the HAFF enable social housing investment?

Under the HAFF,聽, generating an estimated $500M annual return to subsidise housing development that, backed by investment income, would be accounted as 鈥榦ff balance sheet鈥 expenditure. That is, formally sitting outside of the annual budget.

Emulating similar but much smaller frameworks established by several states,聽, it is understood community housing organisations will聽then secure private (debt) finance from institutional investors like superannuation funds to develop 30,000 units in the program鈥檚 first five years, underpinned by government contracts for annual subsidy payments for 25 years.

鈥淐rudely ignoring inflation, the maths of this will see subsidy paid out at $500 million a year for 25 years, summing to $12.5 billion over the period, and therefore implying a per dwelling subsidy totalling $417,000 across the 30,000 unit program,鈥 Prof. Pawson says.

Along with tenants鈥 rents, these subsidy payments will enable the housing providers to meet finance costs 鈥 interest and repayment on institutional debt 鈥 as well as ongoing housing management and maintenance. In other words,聽

鈥淭he upside of this mechanism is that, for a given annual amount of public subsidy, it effectively enables the government to bring forward social housing investment,鈥 Prof. Pawson says.

Expended more conventionally聽, a given annual subsidy spend (e.g. $500 million per year) would generate far fewer dwellings over the first few years of a program, Prof. Pawson says.

鈥淚f the subsidy needed to build each new social housing unit is $417,000, a $500 million capital grant program would give you only about 6000 in the first five years, not 30,000,鈥 Prof. Pawson says.

Read more:聽

But Prof Pawson says there is also a downside to the HAFF.

鈥淥nce the 30,000 homes have been contracted near the start of the program, the income stream generated by the $10 billion HAFF investment is fully committed for the next 25 years,鈥 Prof. Pawson says. 鈥淚n isolation, 30,000 new units will make only a very modest start towards redressing Australia鈥檚聽.

鈥淏ut if governments insist on this form of procurement, extending and expanding the program beyond this tranche will be possible only by boosting the value of the HAFF itself 鈥 for example, by pledging another $10 billion equity investment stake.鈥

Leveraging institutional investment聽

Institutional investors, like Australia鈥檚 superannuation funds, regularly invest in infrastructure assets, like roads, ports and tunnels, but few have a direct stake in social housing 鈥 or, indeed, in any form of rental housing.

鈥淭here鈥檚 potential for social housing to attract institutional investors like superannuation funds, but up until now, Australia has generally lacked the right government policy settings to ensure the returns are comparable with competing risk-adjusted investment options,鈥 Prof. Pawson says.

Importantly, the returns on social housing as an asset class are predicated聽聽ensured via long-term government contracts, such as those expected to be struck under the HAFF. From the investor perspective, it鈥檚 a low-yield, low-risk stake that can form part of a diverse, balanced fund portfolio.

鈥淚n this model, the institutional investor is providing debt, not equity. Their financial input doesn鈥檛 buy them an equity stake in the building,鈥 Prof. Pawson says. 鈥淚nstead, with debt repaid after, say, 25 years, the properties are eventually outright owned by the community housing organisation for retention as low-rent homes in perpetuity.鈥澛

Read more:聽

Large corporations having a stake in social housing might prompt anxieties. But Prof Pawson argues the arrangement could bring added benefits.

鈥淔or the 鈥榖ig end of town鈥, it would give them some skin in the game, in a part of the housing market they haven鈥檛 had much interaction with before,鈥 Prof. Pawson says.

鈥淔rom a strategic point of view, it means those companies will have a vested interest in the vitality and sustainability of social housing and will be motivated to protect and defend it into the future.鈥